May 12, 1942
Treasury anti-inflation tax proposalsThe record shows
that the Treasury in the autumn of 1941 was practically
alone, among responsible groups in the executive and
legislative branches in urging special anti-inflationary
taxes; that other agencies and Congress were apathetic,
and the press violently opposed, to the Treasury's
program formulated in November, 1941; and that there was
no demand for new anti-inflationary taxes on low- income
groups until AFTER the Treasury had presented to Congress
its proposals to meet the $7 billion dollar revenue goal
set by the President in his budget message of January 5,
1942. When an over-all Administration attack on inflation
was under consideration in April, 1942, the Treasury
again stood practically alone, this time in advocating
reliance on voluntary bond purchases rather than further
taxes and compulsory savings plans directed at the
low-income groups.
THE BOSTON SPEECH
On September 9, 1941, Secretary Morgenthau delivered
before the Advertising Clug of Boston an address which
was widely hailed in the press as the first clear call
from a responsible administration lender for an all-out
attack on inflation. He called for heavier taxes in 1942;
larger purchases of Defense Bonds; extended controls over
bank credit and capital expenditures; expansion of the
social security program, with a "separation
wage" contribution from workers to set up reserves
against the day when they might lose their jobs;
reduction of non-essential Federal expenditures; efforts
to increase supplies of consumer goods; and release of
farm surpluses from storage.
THE CHICAGO SPEECH
Three weeks later, speaking to the American Bankers
Association in Chicago, the Secretary again stressed the
danger of inflation. "One indispensable method of
paying for defense without inflation is 'all-out'
taxation, a method that has not yet been tried." The
tax bill next year will have to be genuinely 'all-out'
bill."
The Secretary's Boston speech was well received in the
press, but served editorial writers principally as a
springboard for attacks on the farm bloc. Nowhere was
there significant support for immediate taxes designed to
help check inflation.
The Treasury Department, however, set about
formulating a program of special anti-inflationary taxes.
Two plans served as starting points for the Treasury's
studies of such taxes -- the Shoup report and the Barnard
proposals.
THE SHOUP REPORT
A report prepared under the auspices of the Institute
of Public Administration and the Carnegie Corporation by
Carl Shoup, Milton Friedman, and Ruth Mack, entitled
"Amount of Taxes Needed in June, 1942, to Avert
Inflation", recommended a supplementary income tax,
to be collected at the source, to raise $5 billion
additional revenue and draw off that much excess
purchasing power. They estimated that by June, 1942, the
Government must be collecting at least $5 billion,
perhaps as much as $9 billion, more from consumer incomes
than it would collect under existing law, if a
substantial rise in prices was to be prevented. They
suggested a tax rate of 17 percent on that part of an
individual's income in excess of exemptions of $1,000
(married) and $500 (single) and a $300 credit for each
dependent. The tax rate, they pointed out, might later
have to be increased and exemptions reduced.
THE BARNARD PLAN
On October 16, 1941, Secretary Morgenthau called a
conference of his chief fiscal advisers to consider Mr.
Chester Barnard's program of "family reserves"
and "business stabilization reserves."
The Barnard plan called for: (1) a flat 5% levy on all
incomes above an exemption of $1,000; (2) a special
graduated levy on the increase in incomes of persons
whose incomes had grown larger from one taxable year to
another; (3) mandatory purchase, on a graduated scale, of
"business stabilization certificates" out of
corporate earnings exceeding 6 percent on invested
capital, after taxes; (4) tax inducements for
establishing irrevocable trust funds for payment of
dismissal wages and retirement pay. The additional taxes
on individuals would be credited to the taxpayers as
"family reserves" and repaid gradually after
the emergency, or repaid earlier in case of urgent family
need. The "business stabilization reserves"
likewise would be repaid after the emergency, or earlier
in certain cases.
Secretary Morgenthau expressed great interest in the
Barnard plan and ordered that top flight men from various
Treasury offices be assigned to study the plan carefully.
Out of consideration of the Barnard plan and the
Shoup-Friedman-Mack study, the Treasury's program of
special anti-inflationary taxes gradually took shape.
THE NOVEMBER PROPOSALS
By October 29, 1941, the Secretary's advisers had come
to agree on the main outlines of an anti-inflationary tax
program.
This program placed major reliance on taxation rather
than compulsory savings and on individual income taxes
rather than corporate taxes. Emphasis was placed on
taxation because compulsory savings are, dollar for
dollar, less effective in reducing inflationary pressure
than taxes, involve an increase in the public debt and
post-war commitments under conditions that cannot be
clearly foreseen in advance, and make additional levies
in the form of taxes rather than compulsory savings more
difficult. Further, it was felt that the amount of taxes
required was not yet sufficiently large so that
compulsory saving was essential to soften they blow and
to provide incentive for increased effort. Emphasis was
placed on individual rather than corporate taxes because
the inflationary pressure was arising primarily from
increased individual incomes and because direct measures
were available and were being taken to curtail
non-essential corporation expenditures on capital
expansion.
The major points of the anti-inflationary program
were:
1. The control of inflation required that by June,
1942, tax collections out of consumer income be increased
by from $6 billion to $9-1/2 billion.
This estimate represented a revision of that contained
in the Shoup-Friedman-Mack report based on a series of
technical conferences with representatives from other
Washington agencies. More than 20 persons participated in
these conferences and eight agencies other than the
Treasury Department were represented, among them the
Office of Price Administration, the Office of Production
Management, the Federal Reserve Board, and the Bureau of
the Budget.
2. There was general support for the Social Security
Board's proposed expansion of the social security
program, with increases in payroll taxes (1% increase in
tax on employees for unemployment insurance).
3. There was general agreement that there should be
some form of flat tax on incomes above minimum
exemptions, to be withheld at source of payment, and to
go into effect January 1, 1942. Opinions differed as to
the the rate of the special withholding tax and the
amount which should be credited to the taxpayers as
compulsory savings. A plan representing a median among
the various proposals called for a tax rate of 12-1/2%
with exemptions of $1,000 for married persons and $500
for single persons, and a $300 credit for dependents.
About $0.5 billion of the revenue received form low-
income groups should be credited to taxpayers for return
after the emergency.
4. The impact of these special anti-inflationary taxes
should be balanced by changes in the income tax in the
higher brackets, increased corporation taxes, and the
closing of loopholes in the present law. These additional
measures were to be presented along with the special
anti-inflationary taxation, but with the expectation that
they would be embodied in a separate bill to be enacted
at a later date.
This was substantially the program informally
presented by Secretary Morgenthau to the Ways and Mean
Committee on November 5, 1941. By that time the Treasury
had decided upon a supplementary net income tax of 15
percent, to be withheld at source, with personal
exemptions fixed at $1,500 and $750, and with a $400
credit for dependents, plus the social security tax
increases already mentioned. The plan called for no
compulsory savings.
CONGRESSIONAL ATTITUDE
Secretary Morgenthau invited Senator George and
Chairman Doughton to confer with him concerning the
Treasury proposals. They met on November 5, 1941, and the
Secretary presented the results of the Treasury studies,
pointing out that an inflationary gap of from $5 to $10
billion could be expected in 1942 and recommending a tax
bill to raise about $5 billions. He then outlined how the
Treasury proposed to raise this amount. Both chairmen
thought the request for increases in social security
taxes would bring on a long and heated Congressional
debate. Both felt that Congress had no appetite for a new
tax bill. Congress, they said, was tired and wanted a
vacation. Chairman Doughton added that he thought
Congress would be more interested in getting more tax
revenue than in trying to block inflation through taxes.
It was arranged that Secretary Morgenthau should
informally discuss his proposals with the Ways and Means
Committee. This he did in the afternoon of November 5,
1941. Considerable hostility to the social security
proposals was apparent, and it was generally thought that
any revision of the social security system would involve
a long period of discussion and consideration. Mr.
Robertson indicated approval of social security tax
increases, but wanted an assurance from the White House
that there would be no social security reform message
while the tax bill was under consideration.
The Secretary again met with Senator George and
Chairman Doughton on the morning of November 6, 1941.
Earlier in the morning the Secretary had seen the
President, and he reported that the President had
approved the Treasury proposals. He further reported that
the President had agreed not to send the social security
message to Congress until after Christmas, provided
Congress would immediately start to consider the
Treasury's tax proposals. The Secretary added that the
President said he would be obliged to send a letter to
Chairman Doughton asking for immediate consideration of
the Treasury program in case the Committee decided to
turn it down.
Chairman Doughton was not pleased with these remarks
and proceeded to outline his own ideas of a proper
time-table for considering tax measures. First, loopholes
in the present law should be closed. Reduction on
non-essential Government spending should then be
effected. After these steps had been taken a tax bill, in
his opinion, could be taken up and put through with much
less delay and opposition. He thought the withholding tax
would meet with strong opposition -- solid among
Republicans, considerable among democrats. Senator George
agreed that the program would be strongly opposed in
Congress. Chairman Doughton repeated that he thought the
way to keep prices down was through the price control
bill, not through taxes. He again alluded to restiveness
in Congress and the desire of members to have a vacation.
ATTITUDE OF OTHER ADMINISTRATIVE AGENCIES
On the same day that the Secretary first met with the
Chairman of the Congressional Committees (November 5) Mr.
Eccles and Mr. Paul conferred. Mr. Eccles felt there
would be no serious inflation problem for about a year.
In his opinion, the shift to war industries, temporary
lack of employment, and the impact of existing taxes,
should take care of the situation until about November,
1942. He doubted the effectiveness of a withholding tax,
pointing out it would lead to demands for wage increases
and higher farm prices. To control inflation, he said, it
was necessary to control prices of important commodities
and to impose effective controls on wages and farm
prices. A withholding tax, he thought, would be
politically impracticable until taxes on higher brackets
had been stiffened.
On November 5, 1941, Mr. Henderson addressed a
memorandum to the Supply, Priorities and Allocation Board
entitled "How Fiscal Policy Can Aid the Work of the
SPAB." Having estimated that there would be a
considerable inflationary gap in 1942, he said that chief
reliance must be placed on taxation to close the gap. His
suggested tax program included (1) closing loopholes, (2)
advancing income-tax payment dates, (3) collection of
income tax at source, starting at a rate of 5 percent,
(4) small increase in social security taxes, (5) stiffer
excess profits taxes, and (6) selective excises to
complement price control and curtailment of production
for civilian use. He expressed opposition to compulsory
savings for the time being. These proposals were much
milder as anti-inflationary measures than the proposals
then being developed by the Treasury.
A few days later, November 12, 1941, Secretary
Morgenthau met with Messrs. Eccles and Henderson. Mr.
Henderson felt that no accurate estimate of the
inflationary gap could be made without information from
the O.P.A. concerning plans for converting production to
war purposes. In his opinion it seemed likely that
ordinary production would be so curtailed that there
would be, for a time, less rather than more purchasing
power in the nation until the adjustment had been made
and the adjustment might be a slow process. Mr. Eccles
thought enactment of a withholding tax would not be
politically feasible until loopholes in the present tax
law had been closed, individual surtaxes raised, and the
excess profits tax stiffened. It was arranged that the
technical staffs of the Treasury, O.P.A., and Federal
Reserve Board should meet to work out details of a tax
program.
PRESS REACTION
The Secretary had presented his tax proposals to the
Ways and Means Committee in confidence, to learn whether
they were interested in holding hearings to consider such
a tax program. The proposals, however, leaked out and
were widely reported in the press. The proposals were in
general misunderstood, the 15 percent withholding tax
being regarded as a tax on gross income rather than on
income above exemptions and as a payroll tax rather than
an income tax. Editorial denunciation was prompt and
vigorous. The press assailed the withholding tax as an
indefensible burden on incomes which had not increased as
a result of the defense program, scoffed at the idea that
there was an excess of purchasing power which needed to
be mopped up, and accused the Administration of turning
to taxation as a politically easier way of doing a job
which could only be done by an effective price control
bill.
When the President wrote to Chairman Doughton,
November 8, 1941, to urge immediate consideration of the
Treasury proposals, the press said that the first job of
the Administration was to pass a strict price control
law, restraining wages and farm prices as well as prices
of other commodities. Next in order, the Administration
should cut non-essential expenditures. Then, and only
then, should new taxes be considered as a complementary
measure to check inflation.
The press reiterated its strong opposition t using
social security tax increases as a method of emergency
financing. Changes in the social security system should
be considered quite apart from any program to combat
inflation or raise revenue.
On December 11, 1941, a conference on taxes was held
at the home of Assistant Secretary Sullivan. Budget
Director Smith, Price Administrator Henderson, Federal
Reserve Chairman Eccles, and Mr. Lauchlin Currie were
present from outside the Treasury. In the face of
Congressional lack of interest in special
anti-inflationary taxes, the lack of support for such
program from other Administration leaders, and the strong
press reaction against the Treasury proposals, the plans
for a special withholding tax had been shelved. The
Treasury was still concerned, however, over the problem
of speeding up tax collections to divert purchasing power
from the hands of consumers as quickly as possible.
Should an immediate request be made for authority to
withhold some part of the income tax at source of
payment?
Mr. Mr. Henderson thought that due to dislocation in
industry, the pressure of income on prices would not be
resumed until March, 1942. Beginning in March, he said,
the pressure of income would increase and larger
withdrawals of purchasing power would be necessary. A
plan for speeding up tax collections might be included in
the regular tax bill and then enacted separately if the
bill were delayed. Mr. Eccles seemed to agree with Mr.
Henderson's position. Mr. Currie likewise agreed. He
thought the case for a strong tax bill might be weakened
if there was a prior request for discretion to advance
the date of collection before the regular tax bill was
presented. Mr. Smith took the same position.
PREPARATION OF 1942 TAX PROGRAM
The Treasury then set about preparing its proposals
for a 1942 tax bill. Guided by to reactions of other
agencies to its earlier plans, the Treasury decided to
present a single bill rather than urging the adoption of
special anti-inflationary taxes prior to the enactment of
other changes. The President set a revenue goal of about
$7 billion (plus $2 billion in social security taxes) in
his budget message of January 5 and the Treasury Plan was
designed to raise this amount. In the course of its
preparation during January and February, Mr. Paul
conferred constantly with Mr. Eccles of the Federal
Reserve Board, Mr. Gilbert of the O.P.A., Mr. Colm of the
Bureau of the Budget, as well as with representatives of
other interested agencies. Until the first of March, when
the Treasury proposals were about to be submitted to the
Ways an Means Committee, there were no demands, from
agencies concerned with inflation control, for a higher
tax yield than that proposed by the President and by the
Treasury.
On January 12, 1942, a meeting was held in Mr. Paul's
office to consider a proposal by the Bureau of the Budget
for a tax on value added. This meeting was attended by
representatives of the Bureau of the Budget, and a number
of other agencies outside of the Treasury. Most of the
persons present agreed with the Treasury representatives
in opposing the proposed tax.
From January 25 to February 17, 1942, an Excise Tax
Committee met frequently to consider what excises
Congress should be asked to impose. The Treasury, O.P.A.,
Federal Reserve Board, W.P.B., Bureau of the Budget, and
Staff of the Joint Committee on Internal Revenue
Taxation, were represented on this committee.
Deliberations proceeded on the assumption that a number
of selective excise taxes, rather than a general sales
tax, would be included in the tax program.
ANTI-INFLATION PROGRAM SINCE MARCH 1, 1942
On March 3, 1942, Secretary Morgenthau and Mr. Paul
presented to the Ways and Means Committee the Treasury's
proposals for taxes to raise $7.6 billion.
One day earlier, March 2, Mr. Henderson wrote a letter
to the Secretary, urging the institution of a compulsory
savings plan to raise 5 or 6 billion dollars more than
the revenue goal of the Treasury's tax program.
Mr. Henderson estimated that under the most favorable
circumstances the excess of consumers demand over supply
would be at least $12 billion, even AFTER the increase in
taxes proposed by the Treasury. He expressed fears that
price control and rationing would not be effective to
keep prices down unless a large part of these $12 billion
was diverted from consumers. Accordingly, he recommended
a compulsory savings plan, with exemptions lower than
those granted under the present income tax law.
This marked the beginning of efforts on the part of
several agencies -- Treasury, O.P.A., Bureau of the
Budget, Department of Agriculture, and W.P.B. -- to
formulate an over-all inflation program. Agencies other
than the Treasury insisted on the need of taxes much
heavier, and more directly aimed at low incomes, than
those suggested by the Treasury. After a period of
intensive consideration of various anti-inflation
measures, the program of these various agencies took
definite shape.
Until April 6 there was disagreement on details among
all the agencies. For example, April 3 the
representatives of O.P.A. insisted that the O.P.A. was
strongly opposed to a general sales tax and lower income
tax exemptions which were being urged by some other
agencies. April 6 the O.P.A. united with the other
agencies in recommending a sales tax, lower exemptions,
and compulsory savings.
April 6, 1942, Budget, O.P.A., W.P.B. and Agriculture
informed the Treasury that they were agreed on a tax and
compulsory savings program to yield about $6-1/4 billion
more during the fiscal year 1943 than the Treasury's
program. Their tax program was to supplement an
anti-inflation program calling for freezing of prices,
rents, and wages; drastic restrictions of consumer
credit; and specific rationing. Their tax proposals
consisted of:
1. Lowering personal income tax exemptions to $500 for
single persons and $1,000 for married persons, and a $250
credit for each dependent. Estimated yield - $2 billion.
2. Compulsory savings at the rate of 5 percent on
income, excluding single income earners of $500 or less
and married earners of $1,000 or less. Estimated yield --
$3 billion.
3. A war consumption (sales) tax of 5 percent to take
effect January 1, 1943, which would raise $1-1/4 billion
in the second half of fiscal 1943.
4. An excess profits tax rate of 100 percent (No
estimate on yield).
5. Confiscation of all income above $50,000 or
$100,000 (No estimate on yield).
This group insisted that such a tax and compulsory
savings plan would be more equitable and effective than
an intensified drive to sell War Savings Bonds. Such a
drive, they said, would not raise the required sums of
money unless coercive sales methods were used.
The Treasury stood alone in urging reliance on
voluntary War Bond purchases and in opposing compulsory
savings, a general sales tax, lower income tax
exemptions, and freezing of wages.
|