Memo to Mr. Magill from Mr. Shoup
Plans for Additional Revenue
On December 21, 1937, you asked
that I consider ways of raising (1) $500,000,000 and (2)
$1,000,000, in addition to present tax receipts. On
December 29, I submitted a general memorandum on the
subject, and promised more details in a few days. In a
subsequent discussion, however, we agreed that I had
better use my time on some other problems until this
particular became pressing.
I am taking up this problem again in
the present memorandum, since the imminent passage of the
farm bill, the pressure for additional unemployment
relief funds and (over the longer term) the proposed
increase in armaments might easily increase expenditures
by $1,000,000,000 a year.
THE POSSIBLE BUDGET DEFICIT. -- The
budget for 1939 estimates expenditures at $6.2 billions,
exclusive of debt retirement and also exclusive of $0.7
billions to be credited to old-age, etc., Thus a Federal
"borrowing deficit" of $0.3 billion results,
which, however, does not lead to a sale of Federal bonds
to the banks and the public, if the States' unemployment
trust fund is in a position to absorb as much as the
budget message estimates (i.e., $0.6 billion).
If we take a pessimistic view, we can
conceive of the recovery and relief appropriation for
1939 being raised by about $1.0 billion above the $1.1
billion total estimated for that year in the budget. That
1939 total includes $1.0 for W.P.A. and "Emergency
relief Program," compared with $1.3 for the same
item (all in W.P.A) for 1938. Perhaps a better comparison
is between the 1939 $1.1 total and the (1938) $2.0
billion total for all "recovery and Relief."
The point is, the 1938 total will apparently be increased
by about $0.3 billion, making the 1938 total $2.3 billion
-- compared with the $1.1 billion estimated in the budget
for 1939. An increase of $1.0 billion or even $1.2
billion in the 1939 total therefore appears to be a
possibility.
The 1939 budget allocates $0.6 billion
to the agricultural adjustment program. No one seems to
know how much more the new farm bill will cost, but I
have seen an estimate of $0.3 billion reported in the
press. If business conditions are so bad that the extra
billion is needed for relief, revenues may well fall
below the $5.9 billion estimated for 1939. Suppose there
was a decline of $0.5 billion below this estimate -- then
the effect of the added relief load (using the extreme
figure of $1.2 billion), the added farm expenditure ($0.3
billion) and the decline in revenue ($0.5 billion) would
be an increase of the Federal "borrowing"
deficit to $2.3 billion. The sale of Federal bonds to the
banks and public would, as noted above, be less than
this, by the amount that the states' unemployment trust
fund could absorb. It might not be able to absorb nearly
the $0.6 billion estimated in the budget, however, if
business continued poor. Possibly about $2.0 billion
would have to be borrowed from the banks and the public.
These figures omit consideration of the
added armaments expenditures, which apparently will not
greatly exceed (if at all) $0.1 billion in 1939).
POSSIBLE SOURCES OF ADDED REVENUE --
Under these circumstances what would be the best way to
raise (a) $500,000,000 (b) $1,000,000,000 -- assuming,
for the sake of argument, that either of these sums
should be raised?
For reasons given in my memorandum of
December 29, the choice should be restricted to the
personal income taxes, the death and gift taxes, the beer
tax, the taxes on tobacco products other than cigarettes,
and the miscellaneous excise and stamp taxes. A
manufacturers' sales tax and import duties on coffee,
tea, cocoa, etc., are possibilities, and so is an
increase in the corporation normal tax, but none of these
appear desirable. Increase in the payroll taxes, customs
duties generally, the gallonage tax on spirits, and the
tax on small cigarettes are probably still less desirable
(but the spirits tax might well be increased if the
administrators of the tax think that this could be done
without losing revenue through bootlegging, restriction
of demand of spirits generally, etc.).
ESTATE AND GIFT TAXES. -- First choice
seems to me to be a series of measures to get more money
from the death and gift taxes. The chief problem here is
the lag between enactment of the change and the inflow of
receipts. If the additional money is to be raised, not to
relieve immediate pressure on the Government bond market,
but rather to give assurance of progress toward a
balanced budget, increases in these taxes are specially
suitable. They strengthen confidence in the fiscal
policies of the Government without at once exercising a
deflationary effect. But if an immediate deflationary
effect is needed (as when the market for a government's
bonds is already showing signs of grave weakness), these
increases do not of course act fast enough.
I think we can assume that there will
be no need for an immediate deflationary effect in the
near-term future, and I therefore think the lag in
increased receipts would not be a marked disadvantage,
and might even be an advantage. However, if the matter is
left to drift for a year or so, the answer might have to
be different.
A. The steps that in my opinion could
be taken at once to increase the revenues from the death
taxes and gift taxes are as follows (in addition to
changes already recommended by the sub- committee):
1. Increase the rates of the estate tax
and the gift tax, and lower the specific exemption from
$40,000 to $20,000. The increase in death tax rates could
be somewhat like the recommended in the Haas report of
last August, Vol. V. p. 24(a). This schedule was approved
in the Blough-Shoup report of last September (pp.M-16 to
M-19).
Under the present schedule a net
estate, BEFORE deducting the specific exemption of
$40,000, pays no tax. Under the proposed rates and
exemption it would pay $600, or 1-1/2 per cent. /1/ An
estate of $100,000 now pays $4,200; it would pay $9,000.
An estate of $500,000 now pays $80,400, or 16.1 per cent
-- it would pay $164,900, or 33.0 per cent. /2/ An estate
of $1,000,000 now pays $211,000; it would pay $443,500.
An estate of $5,000,000 now pays $1,900,000, or 38%; it
would pay $2,922,700, or 58%.
This increase in rates and lowering of
exemption might produce an added revenue of somewhere
around $400,000,000 in a normal year.
If serious attention is to be given to
the probability of increasing the estate tax rates and/or
lowering the specific exemption, I suggest that the
statistical section be started at once on the making of
estimates of yield (and not for a "normal
year", but specifically for the fiscal years 1939,
1940, and 1941, assuming the legislation to become
effective as of a given date -- say June 30, 1938 -- and
assuming only moderate business improvement in those
years).
2. Repeal the $40,000 insurance
exemption. This might add $10,000,000 or $20,000,000 to
the revenue, assuming the new high rates to be in force.
3. Eliminate the option to value
property as at death or one year later. (I do not have
any means at hand to estimate even roughly what this
would mean in revenue increase, but for the sake of
saving something, suppose it adds $20,000,000 a year).
4. Increase the rates of the gift tax
to correspond with the increase in the estate tax, and
lower the specific exemption to $20,000. This might yield
an added $10,000,000 or so.
5. Include in the decedent's taxable
estate all property over which he has power of
appointment either general or limited (at present we tax
only if the power is general and is exercised). This
would probably yield more than $10,000,000. It appears
that this provision would be held constitutional except
possibly where the power was extremely limited.
6. Include in the decedent's taxable
estate under Sec. 302(c) the proceeds of insurance on the
decedent's life where he has retained no incidents of
ownership in the insurance (he cannot change the
beneficiary, cannot borrow on it, etc.). This might yield
$10,000,000 a year easily. (At present the gift tax
applies to the premiums when paid). It appears that this
provision would be held constitutional, at least for
policies taken out after 1918.
7. Remove the exemption now granted to
non-resident aliens on transfers (estate tax and gift
tax) of Federal Government bonds. Possibly $5,000,000 a
year is optimistic.
Altogether these changes in the death
and gift tax might add almost half a billion dollars to
the Federal Revenue in the fiscal year 1941. Possibly the
increase in 1940 would be about $0.2 or $0.3 billion.
B. In addition to the steps listed
above, there are others that seem clearly desirable and
that would likewise increase substantially the death tax
and gift tax revenues. They are put in this second group,
however, because they might be more difficult to enact
speedily. They need to be worked on further to smooth out
technical problems. Thus they might imperil the rest of
the program too much to be considered for action this
year.
1. Coordinate the gift tax and the
estate tax by starting the progression of rates on the
estate where they left off with the last gift. This would
increase revenues substantially, but I have no way at
present of computing even an approximate amount.
2. Restrict the exemption to charitable
bequests, perhaps as suggested in the Haas Report (Vol.
V. p. 20, second paragraph).
3. Reduce the relief now given to
property previously taxed within five years, by
graduating the relief as suggested in the Haas Report
(Vol. V, p. 16, first paragraph).
4. Impose some kind of accessions tax
on remainderman interests when they mature (this point
will be developed by Harriss in his forthcoming
memorandum on death and gift taxes).
5. Remove deduction (now allowed where
state law allows it) for support of dependents. Possibly
$2,000,000 or so involved.
INCOME TAXES. -- If revenue is needed
more quickly than the estate and gift taxes will bring
it, the personal income tax seems to me to be the best
source. An increase here would probably have a smaller
deflationary effect on purchases of consumers' goods than
any other increase that would bring the money is an
quickly, and I am still assuming that for the time being
such deflationary effects are not needed. From this point
of view, increases in taxes on the well- to-do and the
wealthy -- say those with incomes above $10,000 or
$15,000 - seems called for. But it is also desirable to
avid the deflationary effects that come from decreasing
willingness to take changes and invest. In a depression
almost every new investment (whether in an old or new
industry) involves a seemingly large element of risk,
either for (1) the new investment or (2) the already
existing investment that has to be pushed out further in
the risk area when new senior capital is put in - for
example, outstanding common stock, when bank loans are
made or new bond issues are floated. A clue to proper
action is given by this supposition: An invest for thinks
of possible new income as being superimposed on the
margin of his existing income, and hence subject to the
marginal tax rate (the bracket rate), of the effective
rate. Thus if a man who is already receiving $50,000
taxable income is asked to invest with the possibility of
adding $6,000 to his income, he tends to think of the
$6,000 as being subject to a 25 per cent Federal income
tax rate (the bracket rate on $50,000 to $56,000). If his
tax is raised by increasing only the rate in, say, the
$20,000-$40,000 rage, his willingness to make this new
investment is probably not decreased. Over the long run
the increase might have a dampening effect, since over
the long run he may plan his investment program more as a
whole, but this memorandum is concerned primarily with
short-run tendencies.
These speculations are too vague to
show just where the rates might best be raised, but I
think they indicate that somewhere in the middle or
lower-middle brackets rather than in the upper-middle or
higher brackets is the place. It might even be advisable
to lower, at the same time, they very highest surtax
rates. The net result could be an increase in total tax,
even for the very wealthiest taxpayers. These taxpayers
would, however, have their tax increased by a smaller
percentage than taxpayers in the lower ranges.
In my memorandum to you on November 26,
1937, on p. 8, there is given a hypothetical
"Schedule X" of surtax rates than more or less
fulfills the conditions set forth above. It might raise
from $100,000,000 to $200,000,000 added revenue in the
fiscal year 1940 and somewhat less in fiscal 1939, if
passed by June 30, 1938. If more revenue than that is
needed, I suggest that Schedule X be strengthened in the
$10,000-$20,000 range rather than in the $20,000- $50,000
range.
As indicated in recent conversations,
it is desirable to allow a carry-forward of business net
losses for six years or so, and also a long carry-forward
of capital losses against capital gains. If this were
done, an increase in the corporation normal tax rate
might be desirable at the same time the surtax rates were
raised as suggested above.
FOOTNOTES
/1/ In these computations it is assumed
that the exemption is constant, not vanishing as
recommended by the Haas report, and that the bracket
schedule, not a totality schedule as recommended by the
Hass Report, is used. These assumptions imply, not
necessarily disagreement with these features of the Haas
report, but a belief that if a program is to be put
through, without much delay, to raise substantial amounts
of revenue, it will not prove feasible to put through, at
the same time, changes in such points of technique. /2/
From here on the tax due is before credit for state
taxes. Roughly it may therefore be regarded as the total
of Federal and state death taxes.
|