TAXES AND THE SOCIAL SERVICES OF GOVERNMENT The
decade now closing has witnessed a tremendous expansion
in relief and welfare activities. In recent years between
18 and 23 million people, or between 13 and 17 percent of
the population, have looked to various welfare programs
for their livelihood; programs which are being provided
at an annual expenditure of approximately four billion
dollars. Compared to these, the corresponding statistics
for the beginning of the decade look like small
fractions.
In the course of this expansion the type of provision
made for the welfare cases has greatly changed. The old
general poor relief of the Twenties has now been replaced
by a variety of specialized measures, including several
categories of public assistance, unemployment insurance,
old-age and survivors' insurance, workmen's compensation
insurance and employment on work relief and public works
programs. In some of these compartments, notably under
the various social insurance schemes, individuals now
receive payments as a matter of right and without
reference to the degree of their destitution.
This expansion has been accompanied also by changes in
the division of financial responsibility, changes in
administrative methods and changes in the methods of
financing. The poor relief of the past decade was very
largely a local governmental activity. The programs of
today involve the cooperative efforts of all governments
-- the Federal, the state, as well as the local
governments.
In the midst of this expansion private welfare
activities have dwindled in quantitative importance. At
present private funds probably account for less than one
percent of total relief expenditures. In the early days
of the decade, private funds were, of course, very
important. While nation-wide data are not available,
statistics for 120 urban areas are clearly indicative of
the national trend. Private funds represented 23-1/2
percent of 1930 and 28.6 percent of 1932 expenditures.
Beginning in 1933 they began to decline in relative
importance and in 1935 accounted for only 1.4 percent of
expenditures from public and private funds for different
types of relief in 120 urban areas. (Children's Bureau,
Publication No. 237 "Trends in different types of
Public and Private Relief in Urban Areas,
1929-1935)," p. 10; Social Security Bulletin Current
Issues.)
Since 1935, the volume of relief expenditures from
private funds has become stabilized. In the 120 urban
areas for which comparable statistics are available,
expenditures by private agencies for the past six years
have approximated one million dollars per month. This is
roughly the same amount as was spent in 1929 from the
same sources in these areas. Between 1929 and 1932
average monthly expenditures from private funds rose from
approximately one million dollars to almost five million
dollars. In 1933 and 1934 with the coming of Federal
programs, expenditures rapidly tapered off to the lower
192 level.
GROWTH AND MAGNITUDE OF PUBLIC WELFARE EXPENDITURES
Governmental expenditures for general relief, public
assistance, work relief programs and emergency public
works have shorn an almost uninterrupted increase from
1933 through 1939. Expenditure for these purposes rose
from approximately $700 million in 1933 to more than $5
billion in 1937. As a result of reductions in work relief
and emergency public works programs in 1938, there was a
temporary decline in that year. In 1939, however,
expenditures for these items were probably near the $4
billion level. If expenditures for social insurance
(unemployment and old-age insurance) are included, total
current costs for the welfare functions probably exceed
$4.5 billion. At the present level of expenditures, this
sum represents a quarter of the combined Federal, state
and local, expenditures. The proportion of total
governmental costs required for this function in 1930 was
approximately one percent.
The bulk of the increase in these expenditures is
accounted for by the various work relief programs,
principally W. P. A. projects. Work relief expenditures
assumed primary importance in 1936. In that year, almost
$2 billion was spent for that purpose. In 1939, such
expenditures together with those for public works
exceeded $3 billion.
In the social insurance items, -- unemployment, and
old-age insurance, --- the expansion has been very
recent. Workmen's compensation payments, for the most
part, a non-governmental cost, is the one type of social
insurance which was already being provided in 1933 and
increased relatively little since then. In contrast,
however, unemployment compensation and old-age insurance,
which were first introduced by the Social Security Act in
1936 and the expenditures for which did not get under way
until 1938, accounted for more than $600 million by 1939.
Another item which contributed to the increase of the
thirties is public assistance. Expenditures for the
public assistance categories, including old-age
assistance, aid to dependent children and the blind,
amounted to $600 million in 1939. This represents an
eight-fold increase since 1933. Even as late as l935,
expenditures for these items amounted to only $100
million. With the adoption of the Social Security Act of
1936, however, these functions expanded rapidly. In 1939,
old-age assistance amounted to more than $400 million and
aid to dependent children to more than $100 million.
EXPENDITURES FOR PUBLIC ASSISTANCE, FISCAL YEAR 1939
Total $ 590,530
Administration 46,382
Payments to Recipients 544,148
a. Old-age assistance 417,681
b. Aid to dependent
children 106,627
c. Aid to the blind 19,840
SOURCES OF FUNDS
The burden of financing the vast increase in welfare
an relief expenditures between 1933 and 1939 had fallen
in large part to the Federal government. In 1933 Federal
expenditures for all these services amounted to less than
$400 million. By 1934, the C. W. A. and F.E.R.A. programs
raised Federal expenditures to 2-1/2 billion dollars.
With the introduction of W. P. A. in 1936, they reached
3- 1/2 billion dollars and remained at that level in
1937. After a drop below 3 billion dollars in 1938, they
were again in excess of 3 billion dollars in 1939. State
and local expenditures during this period also showed a
marked increase. The increase in that instance, however,
is somewhat of a different character. In 1933, reported
State and local expenditures were 350 million dollars. By
1939, they were more than 1-1/2 billion dollars. This
substantial increase was in large part accounted for by
two items, both of which constitute a special kind of
load on State and local revenue sources.
In the first place, approximately one-fourth of State
and local expenditures are accounted for by unemployment
insurance. This activity is financed by special taxes on
payrolls, a tax base which would otherwise not be tapped
by either State or local governments.
Secondly, approximately 500 million dollars or almost
a third of these State and local expenditures are
accounted for by work relief programs. The bulk of these
amounts, represents contributions in materials and
services rather than cash expenditures. Moreover, if my
personal observations of a few years back still apply,
these expenditures represent a much smaller burden on
State and local treasuries than would cash outlays. In
many cases, these sponsors' contributions to projects
consist of the services of regular state and local
employees or result from the diversion of existing state
and local materials and equipment to work projects.
Possibly the word "divert" is itself
misleading. In many instances, state and local moneys
appropriated for highway purposes, for instance, were
eventually reported as work relief expenditures. However,
they were nonetheless spent on highway projects. Road
improvements and road construction projects which, in the
absence of a works program, would have been undertaken in
the normal course of events by local governments were
instead conducted under relief programs.
In 1939, approximately $800,000,000 state and local
funds were expended for general relief and public
assistance purposes. It is in this item that the most
conspicuous increase in state and local expenditures has
occurred in recent years. In 1933, state and local
expenditures for these purposes amounted to little more
than $300,000,000. Today, they are almost three times as
large. There is no doubt that the crux of the state and
local welfare financing problem lies in general relief
and public assistance.
In this limited sphere, -- that is, in the field of
general relief and public assistance, -- the financing
problem is not as pressing today as it has been in the
immediate past. In 1934 and 1935, and more particularly
since 1936, state and local governments have made
substantial provision for these services. The effect of
the Federal government's insistence on state and local
matching of Federal relief expenditures, and more
recently, the effect of the enactment of the Social
Security Act, on state and local appropriations requires
no elaboration.
At the beginning, state and local provision for relief
and welfare was of a temporary and makeshift character.
Funds were diverted wherever they could be found. Bonds
were sold wherever authorizations were available or could
be obtained. Various temporary taxes were enacted. More
recently, however, state and local welfare financing has
been of a more permanent character. Such devices as
diversions and borrowings have declined in frequency of
use. In the last two or three years, more and more of the
states have turned to financing public relief and public
assistance through regular budgetary appropriations.
Although today general revenue are used to finance a
majority of the State public assistance programs,
earmarking of revenues is still a frequent practice. A
survey by the social Security Board of the sources of
welfare funds early in 1940 showed that 15 states derive
their old-age assistance funds entirely from earmarked
revenues, 4 states from both earmarked and general
revenues, and 30 states entirely from general revenues.
The same distribution was found in the financing of aid
to dependent children and the blind.
Viewed dispassionately from the point of view of a tax
student rather than a social worker, earmarking of
revenues is an unwhole- some tendency. Earmarked sources
provided by one legislature in the light of the then
current revenue needs can only impede the optimum
allocation of public funds by subsequent legislatures.
Where such earmarkings are provided by statute they raise
the problem of over- coming the efforts of pressure
groups; where they are created by constitutional
amendments, they require not only the overruling of
pressure groups but that of public inertia as well.
Colorado's experience is illustrative. Here is a State
where constitutionally earmarked funds have for several
years caused financial embarrassment to the State
government. The State constitution, which can be altered
only by a referendum of the voters, allocates to old-age
assistance 85% of a significant segment of the revenues
of the State (namely, 85% of all excise taxes now or
hereafter levied upon retail sales; upon liquor; and upon
inheritance taxes and incorporation fees). Moneys
deposited in the old-age pension funds cannot be
transferred to any other fund. The constitution also
fixed at $45 a month the payment which should be made to
recipients of old-age assistance. Such vital services as
public education have been impaired, at the same time
that old-age assistance has been maintained at a high
level. Attempts to amend the constitution have been
unsuccessful.
Problems of this character, however, have a way of
being solved. Our democratic process may be slow, but in
the end, it always tends to work itself out to the
satisfaction of the majority.
On the whole, the problem of financing welfare
activities, which today confronts state and local
governments does not appear to be particularly
overwhelming. To be sure, some problem areas continue to
exist in different parts of the country, especially on
the local level, but these are not sufficiently numerous
to constitute a national problem. The situation with
respect to the financing of the Federal government's
share of these expenditures is substantially different.
The Federal government is now engaged in a vast national
defense program which will require vast sums of money,
and which will of necessity bring with it a pressure for
reducing expenditures for non-defense purposes. In the
process, relief dollars are likely to become scarcer.
With respect to the problem of unemployment, it is
expected that the defense program will reduce the need
for assistance in this field. Apparently in anticipation
of this effect, the President indicated a few days ago
that defense expenditures must have priority over all
others, that certain types of work projects which are now
carried on will have to be postponed. To some extent,
W.P.A. can be geared into the defense program. This year,
it is planned that 40 percent of the W.P.A. projects will
involve work on national defense projects. In addition,
W.P.A. is engaging in a training program to enable many
of its workers to fit into the defense program.
As to the more distant future, one can only
conjecture. Some tendencies may be noted. It is essential
not to over-emphasize the influence of the possible
increase in employment on the need for a work program. In
addition to the 1,700,000 persons now on W.P.A., there
are six or seven millions of other unemployed persons.
The Assistant Commissioner of W.P.A. pointed out several
days ago, "More jobs are opening up every day as a
result of defense expenditures, but these go primarily'
to skilled workers and do not directly affect the bulk of
those on the W.P.A. rolls. In short, while the, defense
expenditures will exert an influence on the size of the
work program required, they will not remove completely
the need for such a program."
It should also be noted that the defense program will
effect only indirectly, if at all, that portion of the
welfare program which is directed to persons other than
the unemployed. And, as you know, this sector of the
relief program is of considerable magnitude.
Assuming, however, that the defense program will make
a substantial contribution to the liquidation of
unemployment, and that it will reduce the need for other
types of welfare services, how long may we expect this
influence to last? The development stage of the defense
program is likely to produce the greatest amount of
employment. After the plants are constructed and the new
equipment installed, the demand for labor is likely to be
reduced. We shall have built the defense machine and it
would then require only maintenance. When this occurs,
the work-relief applicants will increase again. The
President anticipated the likelihood of an expansion in
the works program sometime in the future when he stated
recently that it is desirable to build up a back-log of
plans for projects, with which a future slack in
employment could be taken up.
It is none too early to recognize the likelihood of a
post- defense relapse in unemployment, and to plan to
meet the situation. How great that relapse will be none
can tell. At all events, we should prepare for the
contingency that present unemployment insurance benefit
provisions will be inadequate to absorb the shock.
|