REVENUE PROGRAM FOR 1943 -- 3. THE SALES TAX AND
THE SPENDING TAX
During the legislative proceedings on the 1942 Revenue
Bill, the Treasury (1) opposed flat rate general sales
taxes, (2) opposed a progressive retail sales tax, and
(3) recommended a spendings tax.
FLAT RATE GENERAL SALES TAXES
The Treasury opposed flat rate sales taxes primarily
for two reasons: (1) they fail to protect a basis minimum
standard of living, and (2) the administrative machinery
needed for any sales tax cannot be established during the
war because of the shortages of labor and equipment, if
simultaneously the income tax is to be put on a pay-as-
you-go basis by instituting a system of collection at
source.
Of the flat rate sales taxes, the Treasury prefers the
retail sales tax because is would involve lose pyramiding
than the manufacturers' or wholesalers' tax and would
interferes least with the administration of the price
ceilings. Unfortunately, is also the most difficult to
administer because of the multitude of retail outlets.
/1/
PROGRESSIVE RETAIL SALES TAX
Several independently developed plans for a
progressive retail sales tax have recently been
suggested. This type of tax would meet one of the
Treasury's primary objections to the sales tax -- the
minimum standard of living would be protected. Under
these plans tax- free coupons would be issued to cover a
certain minimums of expenditures. Additional books of
coupons would be issued taxable at the initial sales tax
rate, and still additional books would be available at
successively higher tax rates. /2/
A progressive retail sales tax would constitute an
entirely satisfactory source of war-time finance if it
could be administered reasonably well without a * * * and
costly compliance system. It would not only protect a
minimum standard of living, but it would be on efficient
anti-inflationary measure since the tax could be
collected currently bit by bit as the money is spent. At
the same time it would not have the regressivity that is
the major disadvantage on grounds of equity of the flat
rate sales tax.
The two main weaknesses of a progressive retail sales
tax are (1) the difficulties of administration and
compliance, and (2) the tax base is too small to permit
successful progression.
A progressive retail sales tax would involve all the
administrative difficulties of any retail sales tax and
others to best. Careful and mostly registration of
consumers would be required to prevent persons from
obtaining more than one tax-free set of coupons and to
prevent persons from purchasing additional coupons at tax
rates lover than these provided in the enacted schedule.
Some multiple registration and evasion of proper tax
payment could not be prevented. More important, it would
be element impossible to prevent the transfer on unused
stamps -- either unused exemption stamps if exemptions
were provided, or unused low-rate stamps. Persons who had
no use for the exemption stamps or for low-rate stamps
would sell them to persons whose spendings were larger
than the exempt amount or whose spendings were in higher
rate brackets. Such transfers would be in the mutual
interest of both parties. In practice, it would probably
be preferable to permit such transfers freely rather than
be attempt the impossible task of preventing them. The
feasibility of a progressive retail sales tax either with
or without exemptions would, therefore, even to hinge
very largely on the development of a practical plan for
preventing the transfer of coupons.
Less important but will substantial either
administration and compliance problems would be noted:
(1) The printing and distribution of coupon booklets to
individuals in denominations suitable for retail
purchases would require substantial additional personnel
and equipment even if existing agencies such as banks and
post offices were to be utilized. (2) In addition to
ration coupons, individuals would nee to have on band at
all times sufficient sales tax coupons to cover their
retail purchases. This would be a source of considerable
inconvenience. (3) Retail purchase made by business
concerns would have to be exempted from the graduated tax
rates. This exemption would complicate tax administration
and would create opportunities for evasion. (4) A
continuous check on retailers and auditing of their
accounts would be required to insure the collection of
the coupons by retailers and to prevent them from selling
coupons collected from purchases instead of turning them
over the tax- collecting agency.
The second major weakness of the progressive retail
sales tax is that the tax base is relatively small,
leaving little room for progression under may plan
designed to raise substantial amounts of revenue. As with
any retail sales tax, it is not feasible to tax certain
classes of expenditures such as expenditures on domestic
service, professional service, rent, and similar items.
With total spending of about $70 billion, this means that
the base would be net more than about $50 billion before
exemptions. Exemptions would reduce the base still
farther. For example, suppose only $300 of free coupons
were issued to cover expenditures for each adult and $150
for each child. This would involve the issuance of free
coupons covering over $30 billion of expenditures in the
aggregate, leaving less than $20 billion in the base.
With a base no small, there is little room for
progression. Impose the first rate bracket is made $300
for each adult and $150 for each child, or the * * * as
the exemptions. This would involve first bracket coupons
covering aggregate spendings of over $30 billion -- more
than the entire base. The most that would be feasible, if
exemptions were permitted, would therefore be a flat rate
tax above exemptions.
The considerations that limit progressivity if
exemptions are allowed will also limit the possible
progression in the absence of exemptions. A rate bracket
of $300 for each adult and $150 for each child would
account for ever $30 billion of expenditures. With a
total base of $50 billion only about two such rate
brackets would be feasible. There would be many
individuals whose expenditures would be above these two
brackets, but most of them would be able to secure
coupons at lower bracket rates from persons whose
expenditures were less than the sum of the two brackets.
SPENDING TAX
The Treasury recommended a spendings tax to the Senate
Finance Committee in a special public hearing which
interrupted the Executive Sessions. /3/ The case for the
spending tax was stated by the Secretary as follows:
"The legislative which we are proposing has a
double purpose. The first purpose is to draw into the
Treasury substantial additional funds out of the earnings
and savings of the people. The second purpose is even
more important. It is to reduce consumer spending
directly by withdrawing funds otherwise available for
expenditure, and to reduce it also indirectly by creating
a strong tax incentive to saving . . . . .
"Revenue is not the sale purpose, nor even the
primary purpose . . . . of these proposals. Their main
purpose in to restrict consumer spending so that, as far
as possible through fiscal means, we may avoid the * * *
of inflation in the huge financing program that we have
ahead of us . . . . .
"The control of prices is of course not
exclusively a fiscal problem. But with full allowance for
all that can be done through price regulation, rationing
and other devices to control supply. I think that we, who
are jointly responsible for tax policy and legislation,
shall be doing very much less than our full duty if we do
not deal with the problem as effectively as possible in
the fiscal field. What I have presented is a method --
and the best method the Treasury has been able to devise
-- for accomplishing this result."
The spendings tax is more unitable to the needs of the
present situation than the income tax. It also has
several advantage over the flat rate sales tax an the
progressive retail sales tax.
An advantage of the spendings tax over the income tax
is that it makes a more direct attack on consumer
spending. The income tax is imposed on spendings that
need to be curtailed and on savings that need to be
increased. The spendings tax is imposed only on
spendings. In the second place it is difficult to extend
the income tax indefinitely without imposing undue
hardship on persons with large fixed obligations to repay
debt, to pay insurance premiums or to make other types of
regular savings. Expenditures for these purpose do * * *
little, if any, inflationary pressure on prices. The
spendings tax can be used beyond the point to which the
income tax can be pushed without sacrifice of equity.
The Treasury's recommendation on the spendings tax in
1942 was not intended to reflect that view that the
income tax should not be increased beyond the 1942 rates.
In increasing the income tax the rate of increase as well
as the absolute level of the tax must be takes into
account. It is not politic to take away from the people
by taking their income, all at one time, the entire
amount needed to bring about the readjustment of living
standards which the current war situation requires. The
spendings tax leaves the income in the hands of the
people if they curtail expenditures.
The chief advantages of a spendings tax over a sales
tax are as follows: /4/ (1) Under a spendings tax it is
feasible to protect a minimum standard of living by
exempting a minimum of expenditures; under a sales tax
this can be done only partially and loss satisfactorily
by exempting classes of goods such as food. (2) A
spendings tax, which in a sense is a general expenditure
rationing device, can go a long way to substitute for
rationing of specific commodities. In conditions of short
supply, the liberal purchases of these with high incomes
need to be restrained by rationing if those with low
incomes are to get the essentials for efficiency and for
the maximum war effort. It is impossible to impose a
sales tax at sufficiently high rats to discourage luxury
spending without imposing an undue burden on the great
passes of the people. (3) The sales tax is loss effective
than a spendings tax as a brake upon consumer spending
and prices, first, because it affects the parity prices
of form products and also, because it is administratively
difficult to include services in the tax base, it reaches
a smaller amount of consumer spending.
The spendings tax also has certain advantages over a
progressive rate retail sales tax. Many of the
administrative and compliance problems, as, for example,
the problem of trafficking in coupons, would be entirely
avoided.
But the spendings tax itself in net free from various
administrative difficulties of its own. The final
liability under the spendings tax would not be determined
until after the close of the year. It would be computed
at the same time as the regular income tax and on the
same form. The spendings tax would, however, be of little
immediate value as an anti-inflationary instrument if the
actual collection of the tax were delayed this long.
Consequently, the tax will have to be collected currently
during the year by (1) collection at source from income
received in the form of wages and salaries, interest and
dividends; and (2) quarterly returns of persons with
income from other sources and for persons in the higher
spendings tax brackets. The difference between the
ultimate liability and the amount collected during the
year would be adjusted in the final year- end return. The
quarterly returns would involve a serious administrative
difficulty. So also would the adjustment at the en of the
year. In order to check on the ultimate liability shown
on the year-end return, information would be needed that
is not now available for income tax purposes, for
example, information on bank deposit at the beginning and
end of the year, purchases of securities and the like.
One source of looseness for the first year or so of
operation would be the extreme difficulty, if not
impossibility, of checking on the amount of cash, as
distinguished from bank accounts, in the hands of
individuals at the beginning of the period.
CONCLUSIONS
1.Study of the latest available date on consumer
expenditures indicates that it is possible to protect a
minimum standard of living without contributing to
inflationary pressure. The figures show, for example,
that individuals in the per capita net income class of
less than $00 account for less than 8 percent of the
total attempted consumption of all individuals estimated
for calendar year 1943. (See Table 1 appended). These
data substantiate the position which the Treasury took in
opposition to a general sales tax in 1942 and indicate
that the Treasury should continue in 1943 to oppose all
types of sales taxes which unnecessarily impinge upon
minimum standards of living.
2. Despite the shortcoming of the spendings tax, the
developments in the ration and price control areas since
the enactment of the 1942 Revenue Bill indicate than it
would be highly desirable for the Treasury to renew its
recommendation for a spendings tax in 1943. Public
resistance to price ceiling threats the inflation-control
program and the stability of our economy. In these
circumstances, the spendings tax would seen to have merit
as a measure short of general expenditure rationing. This
would especially be true if the Congressional resistance
to higher taxes and even to compulsory leading were to
develop for short of the amounts necessary to control the
price situation.
Treasury Department December 23, 1942
Division of Tax Research
Table 1
(PART 1)
Estimated distribution of individuals, total income,
net income, state and Federal personal taxes under the 1942 Act,
consumption, and savings and gifts, by per capita /1/
net income classes Calendar year 1943
_____________________________________________________________________
Per capita /1/ Number of Total
net income equivalent income
classes adults /2/ /3/
(thousands)
$ 0 - $400 25,000 6,724
400 - 800 37,000 24,935
800 - 1,200 26,200 29,414
1,200 - 1,600 10,580 16,842
1,600 - 2,000 4,690 9,815
2,000 - 2,500 2,890 7,601
2,500 - 3,000 1,515 4,930
3,000 - 4,000 1,456 5,957
4,000 - 5,000 597 3,164
5,000 - 10,000 766 6,128
10,000 and over 306 9,490
Total 111,000 125,000
CONTINUATION TABLE 1 PART 2
___________________________________________________________________
Net Personal Total Attempted Savings
income taxes income consump- and
/4/ /5/ after taxes tion gifts
___________________________________________________________________
Aggregate amounts
(million of dollars)
5,924 5 6,719 6,034 685
22,083 583 24,352 20,535 3,817
25,642 2,114 27,300 22,129 5,171
14,485 1,630 15,212 11,974 3,238
8,328 1,121 8,694 6,656 2,038
6,393 971 6,630 4,871 1,759
4,125 690 4,240 2,993 1,247
4,984 925 5,032 3,438 1,594
2,641 508 2,656 1,722 934
5,132 1,273 4,855 3,003 1,852
7,918 4,480 5,010 2,717 2,293
Total 107,655 14,300 110,700 86,072 24,628
AVERAGE PER CAPITA /1/
$ 0 - $400 1 $269 $237 /6/ $269 $241 $28
400 - 800 1 674 597 $16 658 555 103
800 - 1,200 1 1,123 979 81 1,042 845 197
1,200 - 1,600 1 1,592 1,369 154 1,438 1,132 306
1,600 - 2,000 1 2,093 1,776 239 1,854 1,419 435
2,000 - 2,500 1 2,630 2,212 336 2,294 1,685 609
2,500 - 3,000 1 3,254 2,723 455 2,799 1,976 823
3,000 - 4,000 1 4,091 4,423 635 3,456 2,361 1,095
4,000 - 5,000 1 5,300 4,424 851 4,449 2,884 1,565
5,000 - 10,000 1 8,000 6,700 1,662 6,338 3,920 2,418
10,000 and over 1 31,013 25,876 14,641 16,372 8,879 7,493
FOOTNOTES TO TABLE |
|
/1/ In computing per capita net income,
spendings, savings, etc., each dependent is
counted as one-half and adult, e.g., a family of
husband and wife and two dependents is counted as
three equivalent adults. If the family income is
$1,800, the per capita income is $600. /2/
Number of potential taxpaying units if there were
no exemptions and if the present advantage to
filing separate returns were retained.
/3/ Corresponds to income payments.
/4/ Total income less tax-exempt income and
deductible items: taxes, interest paid,
contributions, etc.
/5/ Includes Federal and State personal income
taxes and estate and gift taxes; excludes
post-war credit part of Victory tax.
/6/ Less than $.50.
|
|