![]() |
||||||||||
|
||||||||||
MEMORANDUM P MANUFACTURERS' EXCISE AND SPECIAL TAXES Carl Shoup Appendix 1. Taxes On Oleomargarine, Adulterated and Process or Renovated Butter, filled Cheese, Mixed Flour and White Phosphorous Matches. Appendix 2. Federal Control of Commodity Exchanges on Which Commodities Are Sold For Future Delivery Reavis Cox MEMORANDUM P MANUFACTURERS' EXCISE AND SPECIAL TAXES Tables Yield of Jewelry Tax Soft Drinks Tax Revenue Admissions Tax Revenue Yield of Insurance Taxes 1918-1922 Yield of Tax on Telephone, Telegraph, Cable, and Radio Messages Yield of Transportation Taxes Table of Contents Summary of Recommendations Miscellaneous Taxes in General Subject of Present Memorandum Duplications of Certain Parts of Other Memoranda Revenue Aspects of the "All Other" Taxes Basic Reasons for "All Other" Taxes Certain Indirect Taxes Grouped According to Income Levels of Ultimate Taxpayers Certain Desiderata in Indirect Taxation Summary of Conclusions from a Revenue Point of View Expiration Dates of Present Taxes Description and Analysis of the Several Taxes Manufacturers' Excise taxes Candy Cameras and Lenses Chewing Gum Dirk Knives, etc. Electrical Energy Fans Firearms and Ammunition Furs Jewelry Mah-jongg etc. Sets Matches Patent Medicines Radio Parts, Radio-Phonographs, Records, Pianos, etc. Refrigerators Smoking Accessories Soft Drinks:-General Description Soft Drinks: Historical Summary Sporting Goods Thermos Bottles Toilet Articles: General Description Toilet Articles: Historical Summary Vending Machines Miscellaneous Excise and Special Taxes Admissions: General Description Admissions: Historical Summary Art Works Checks Clothing, Luxury Club Dues and Initiation Fees House Furnishings Insurance Passage Tickets Playing Cards Pleasure Boats Powers of Attorney and Proxies Produce (Sales for Future Delivery) Promissory Notes Real Estate Transfer Sale Deposit Box Leases Security Issue Security Transfer Telephone, Telegraph, Radio, and Cable Facilities Transportation Trunks, Purses, etc. Umbrellas Watches, Glasses, etc. Miscellaneous Summary of Recommendations (a) In general, the taxes discussed in this memorandum should be retained only in an emergency. Few if any of them are suitable for use as permanent elements of the fiscal system. (b) If some of these taxes must be retained temporarily, certain of them are decidedly more desirable than others. Details are given in the section below, "Summary of Conclusions from a Revenue Point of View", where the taxes are divided into four groups. Preference should be given to the taxes on toilet articles (except dentifrices and soap), radio and radio parts, electrical energy (if shifted to consumers), and admissions, and to a low rate tax on real estate transfers. (c) Taxes on articles used almost exclusively by the wealthy yield little revenue, and slight income-tax increases should be substituted for them. (d) Some change is needed in the camera tax if it is to be retained; the tax should apply to parts of cameras, or should be replaced by a tax on camera films. (e) Under the radio tax, the complete radio set should be taxable, with provisions to eliminate double taxation. (f) The penalty provisions of the admissions tax need strengthening. (g) The wording of the club dues tax should be altered. Miscellaneous Taxes in General SUBJECT OF PRESENT MEMORANDUM. -- "The present memorandum deals with a miscellaneous group of Federal internal revenue taxes, not readily designated by any one name. Most of them are "indirect" taxes, in the sense that they are commonly thought to be shifted by the payers to other persons, ultimately to the final consumer. They include all the Federal internal revenue taxes other than the taxes on estates and gifts (see memoranda by Walradt), excess profits, capital stock, and automobiles and related products (see memoranda by Bryan), income (see memoranda by Blakey and Shoup), liquor (see memorandum by Williamson), tobacco and processing-tax subjects (see memoranda by Cox). The most important items considered here, from a revenue viewpoint, are the taxes on admissions, checks, communications (telephone, telegraph, etc.), electrical energy, transfers of capital stock, and a group of manufacturers' "excise" taxes on certain luxuries or semi-luxuries, chiefly articles of fur, jewelry, refrigerators, sporting goods, and toilet preparations. DUPLICATIONS OF CERTAIN PARTS OF OTHER MEMORANDA. -- To discuss these taxes adequately the writer has found it necessary to make a few remarks concerning certain taxes treated exhaustively in other memoranda, and the first part of this memorandum will be devoted to a general survey of the Federal revenue system exclusive of taxes on excess profits, estates, gifts, and income. These taxes can be grouped together and omitted from consideration in this memorandum because (a) the reasons for their existence are markedly different from those usually applicable to the other taxes, and (b) their continued existence, with the possible exception of the tax on excess profits, seems assured. Not all of the taxes considered in this memorandum can be called "indirect," and the term "all other taxes" is therefore used in the following paragraphs, this term being taken to mean all other than the four taxes noted above. REVENUE ASPECTS OF THE "ALL OTHER" TAXES. -- These "all other" taxes (including customs duties), although increasing in absolute amount of revenue yielded, furnished a steadily declining share of the total Federal tax revenue from 1914 through 1918. From then until 1923 their relative importance increased as income tax rates were reduced, but from 1924 through 1931 their share declined. The last three years have shown a marked increase in their relative importance. The following figures show the percentage of total Federal tax revenue furnished by these "all other" taxes, INCLUDING CUSTOMS DUTIES, in 1903 and from 1914 to date: 1903 100 * * * * * * * 1914 91 1915 87 1916 83 1917 65 1918 25 1919 34 1920 29 1921 31 1922 37 1923 43 1924 42 1925 40 1926 38 1927 33 1928 34 1929 33 1930 32 1931 32 1932 41 1933 56 1934 69 It will be noted that in 1934 these "all other" taxes (including customs duties) played a relatively greater role than for any year since 1916, when the income tax was being collected at rates that now appear extremely low. If customs are excluded from the "all other" taxes, but not from the revenue total, the percentage become: 1903 45 * * * * * * 1914 48 1915 53 1916 54 1917 43 1918 20 1919 29 1920 23 1921 25 1922 27 1923 25 1924 26 1925 23 1926 21 1927 16 1928 17 1929 16 1930 16 1931 19 1932 24 1933 45 1934 58 It is of interest to note that the peak percentage is the one shown for 1934. The change in the nature of the Federal taxing system that has occurred in the past two years is somewhat exaggerated by the figures above. From the viewpoint of revenue yield the data of course tell the true story; the business depression, however, masks the drastic increases in income tax rates, and the natural lag in collection does not permit the data through 1934 to show the full effect of recent increases in estate tax and gift tax rates. Furthermore, many of the indirect taxes have expiration dates in 1934 and 1935, and the processing taxes, although tagged with no expiration dates, are presumably to last only as long as the agricultural crisis. Bearing in mind these important qualifications, one may still say that from the revenue standpoint the Federal tax system in 1929-30 resembled that of England, whereas today it resembles that of one of the great indirect-taxing countries, France. Every indirect tax imposed by the French National Government is likewise levied by the Federal Government, with the important exceptions of the general sales tax and the taxes on land and water transportation, and with a few relatively unimportant exceptions. /1/ On the other hand, France levies no special taxes on a number of articles taxed by the Federal Government. /2/ True, a mere list of taxes may be deceptive, and in comparison with France it must be recalled that State and local revenues bulk large in this country and are raised chiefly from the property tax. BASIC REASONS FOR "ALL OTHER" TAXES. -- Were it not for political and administrative difficulties, the writer believes that the "all other" taxes, even in times such as these when a large amount of revenue is required, should play an almost insignificant role in the Federal fiscal policy--with the exception of taxes whose proceeds are spent chiefly for the benefit of the group taxed, as is true to a certain extent of the gasoline tax. The income, death, gift (and excess profits) taxes could achieve any purely fiscal aims that are set for the "all other" taxes /3/ and in addition could reach objectives beyond the power of the latter. /4/ With respect to non-fiscal aims (e.g. restriction of consumption of spirits, "subsidy" of certain manufacturing and agricultural interests through the tariff), which are in a measure achieved by indirect taxes, the presumption is that these aims could be reached more nearly by non-tax measures. The validity of the statements above can best be tested by reference to one of the "all other" taxes. Consider the tax on admissions. Why are admissions taxed, and not salt? Obviously, one answers, because the latter is a necessity that even the poverty-stricken must have, whereas purchase of the former is evidence, if not of luxury, at least of a well-being that forms a basis for equitable taxation. It is clear, however, that an income tax can, on paper at least, be more closely adjusted to the relative well-being of various citizens than can the admissions tax or any combination of such "all other" taxes. Why, then, is a certain amount of revenue obtained from an admissions tax rather than from the taxes on income, death, etc.? One of the chief answers is: political and administrative difficulties. For instance, there may be many persons who spend an appreciable amount on admissions and hence pay the admissions tax, but who cannot, for political and administrative reasons, be asked to pay the same amount instead directly on their wages, salary, and other income. A further answer sometimes given is that the person whom it is desired to reach has no net income during certain years of the depression, especially if "income" is taken in a broad sense (e.g. after deduction of losses). Sometimes this answer is expanded to the extent of saving that the country as a whole has not the net income (as defined by the tax law) to carry on the Government. These two factors in the problem -- political or administrative difficulties and absence of taxable income -- must now be examined further. The political or administrative difficulties will first be considered. For purposes of further illustration, it is necessary to divide all those who spend money on admissions into two classes: (a) those whose taxable income is so low that they are not at present subject to the income tax, and (b) those who are subject to the income tax. It is probable that political and administrative objections to substitution of the income tax for the admissions tax are more powerful with respect to the first group than the second. For the first group the substitution would mean installation of tax consciousness and collection of small amounts of money. For the second group it would merely mean an increase in rates. Indeed, so marked is the difference that in the mind of the present writer there is raised a PRIMA FACIE presumption against any of the "all other" taxes whose yield comes (ultimately) from persons now subject to the income tax; the political and administrative obstacles faced in attempting to substitute higher income tax rates for such taxes should not be insuperable even in these times, if the matter is properly presented to the public. It is with the first group (a) above that the real difficulty lies. An important question now arises: Of the indirect tax revenue now collected or to be collected by the Federal Government, how much rest ultimately as a burden upon the those who are subject to the income tax? As with most fiscal questions, no precise answer can be given, but a first approximation may be reached by noting which of the "all other" taxes are probably paid almost wholly by those subject to the income tax. There must be left to one side, for the moment, the more important indirect taxes (e.g. on tobacco and liquor) that strike both classes. The following taxes probably rest ultimately upon few if any persons not subject to the income tax, although there may be considerable doubt on this point with respect to the taxes on cameras, checks sporting goods, firearms. The figures give the yield in 1933-34 (in millions of dollars) except for those taxes whose 1935 yield is certain to be quite different from that of 1934, owing to changes in rate or scope or effective period. In these cases estimates for 1935 are used. Capital Stock (linked with excess profits tax) 80.2 Bonds of indebtedness, issues of capital stock, 16.3 deals of conveyance, etc. (rate increases lapse June 30, 1935, on bond issues and stock issues; bond transfer and real estate conveyance taxes repealed as of same date) Transfers of capital stock (rate increase lapses 38.0 June 30, 1935) Sales of produce (future delivery) (rate returns 4.5 /a/ to 1 cents JULY 1, 1935) Silver bullion transfers (effective 1934-35) 0.0 /c/ Articles made of fur, sold by manufacturer 4.0 /a/ for $75 or more (lapses June 30, 1935) Jewelry, etc. sold by manufacturer for 1.3 /a/ $25 or more (lapses June 30, 1935) Mechanical refrigerators 5.5 (lapses June, 30, 1935) Sporting goods (lapses June 30, 1935) 3.8 Firearms, shells and cartridges, and 2.6 pistols, etc. (except as to pistols and revolvers, lapses June 30, 1935) Cameras and lenses (lapses June 30, 1935) 0.4 Leases of safe deposit boxes (no lapsing date) 2.7 Checks, drafts, etc. (lapses Dec. 31, 1934) 41.4 Club dues and initiation fees (no lapsing date) 6.0 ------- Total 206.7 /b/ FOOTNOTES TO TABLE /a/ Confidential estimate for 1934-35, made by Section of Financial and Economic Research. Data for 1933-34 are not useful here because the scope or rate of the tax was changed by the 1934 Revenue Act. /b/ The short-lived dividends tax, which yielded $50.2 million in 1933-34, is not included. /c/ The yield from this source will apparently be negligible. END OF FOOTNOTES In contrast stand the rest of the "all other" taxes, which are ultimately paid in part by those who are not subject to the income tax (figures, in millions of dollars, represent actual or estimated yield as explained on preceding page). Customs duties 313.4 Liquor 330.2 /a/ Tobacco 425.2 Playing cards 4.4 Lubricating oils (lapses June 30, 1935) 25.3 Brewer's wort, etc. (lapses June 30, 1935) 3.1 Matches (lapses June 30, 1935) 7.0 Gasoline 170.0 /a/ Electrical energy (lapses June 30, 1935) 33.1 Tires and tubes (lapses June 31, 1935) 27.6 Toilet preparations (lapses June 30, 1935) 10.8 Automobiles (lapses July 31, 1935) 37.6 Automobile accessories (lapses July 31, 1935) 5.7 Radio sets, phonograph records, etc. 3.2 (lapses June 30, 1935) Chewing gum (lapses June 30, 1935) 0.6 /a/ Telephone, telegraph, radio, and cable 19.3 facilities, etc. (lapses June 30, 1935) Transportation of oil by pipe line 10.4 (lapses June 30, 1935) FOOTNOTE TO TABLE /a/ Confidential estimate for 1934-35, made by Section of Financial and Economic Research, used for the liquor taxes because the spirits tax was effective only for part of 1933-34, for the gasoline tax because of a rate change in 1934, and for chewing gum because the data for 1933-34 are combined with those for the recently repealed candy tax. END OF FOOTNOTE Admission (on June 30, 1935 exemption returns to $3) 14.6 Oleomargarine 1.5 Narcotics 0.5 Processing taxes 371.4 -------- Total 1,814.9 When the figure $207 million is contrasted with that of $1,815 million, there is at least an indication that a large part of the "all other" tax revenue rests as a burden on those not subject to income tax. The "all other" (chiefly indirect) tax structure therefore appears to be based in large part on a feeling that political or administrative difficulties prevent lower exemptions under the income tax, rather than on a desire to reach the well-to-do classes through channels other than the income tax. To a certain, extent, however, the other factor noted above -- drop in taxable income -- has played a part. Indeed, looking at the national economy as a whole, one may say that there probably was no net income, in the sense in which "net income" was defined under the 1928 Revenue Act, in 1930-31 and 1931-32. Some income appeared for tax purposes, nevertheless, because the gross losses were not distributed among persons PRO RATA with their gross incomes. Considering only the classes not subject to income taxation, probably one may say that even in 1930-31 and 1931-32 they did have income which would have been taxable had the exemptions been lower, and that this income was tapped, instead, through a number of the "all other" taxes noted above. The following list, showing the "all other" taxes introduced by the Revenue Acts of 1932 and 1934, the N. I. R. Act of 1933, the liquor taxing acts of 1933 and 1934, and the customs duties of 1930 and subsequent years, is of interest in this connection (a question mark (?) indicates estimate rather than actual yield data): Yield, 1933-34 Group A (burden on in millions of income-tax payers) dollars ------------------ -------------- Capital stock (linked with excess profits tax) 80.2 Transfer of bonds of indebtedness; conveyance 10.0(?) of real estate; and 100 per cent increase on issues of bonds Increase of 100 per cent of rate on stock transfers 19.0(?) Increase of 400 per cent on sales of produce for 5.0(?) future delivery /1/ Use of yachts and boats /2/ 0.2 Articles made of fur /3/ 7.7 Jewelry, etc. /4/ 4.7 Mechanical refrigerators 5.5 Sporting goods 3.8 Firearms, etc. (except pistols and revolvers) 2.0(?) Cameras and lenses 0.4 Lenses of safe deposit boxes 2.7 Checks, drafts, etc. 41.4 ------- Total 182.6 FOOTNOTES TO TABLE /1/ Reduced to 200 per cent by 1934 Revenue Act /2/ Repealed by 1934 Revenue Act /3/ Sales under $75 exempted by 1934 Revenue Act /4/ Sales under $25 exempted by 1934 Revenue Act END OF FOOTNOTES Group B (part of burden on non-income-taxpayers) Customs duties 2 /1/ Liquor 258.9 Lubricating oils 25.3 Brewers' wort, etc. 3.1 Matches 7.0 Gasoline 202.6 Electrical energy 33.1 Tires and tubes 27.6 Toilet preparations 10.8 Automobiles 37.6 Automobile accessories 5.7 Radio sets, phonograph records, etc. 3.2 Candy and chewing gum 4.9 Soft drinks /3/ 4.7 Telephone, etc. 19.3 Pipe lines 10.4 Admissions: lowering of exemption from 13.0(?) $3 to 40 cents Processing taxes 371.4 ------------- Total 1,038.6 plus customs (?) FOOTNOTES TO TABLE /1/ It appears impossible even roughly to estimate the part of the customs yield traceable to rate changes since 1929. /2/ Candy tax repealed by 1934 Revenue Act /3/ Repealed by 1934 Revenue Act END OF FOOTNOTES As these figures indicate, the changes that have been made in the "all other" taxes since the depression started accounted (aside from customs duties) in 1933-34 for only $183 million in revenue from taxes that fall almost entirely upon those subject to income tax and, on the other hand, accounted for $1,039 million from taxes falling at least in part on those not subject to income tax. Although-several necessary qualifications can be thought of, the general implication of these figure seems to the writer to be (supposing a given amount of revenue had to be raised) that the growth of the "all other" taxes in recent years has been due more to fear of political and administrative consequences of lower personal exemptions than to the absolute shrinkage of income (as defined by tax law) throughout all sections of the population. To the extent that this implications is justifiable, repeal of any large amount of the "all other" taxes cannot be counter-balanced by merely increasing rates of the present income tax unless the Government is willing to make a decided shift of part of the present tax burden from the shoulders of the poor and lower middle classes to those of the upper middle classes and the well-to-do. If it is desired to repeal many of these "all other" taxes and yet make no decided shift in the distribution of the tax burden, the Government must be willing to instill tax consciousness into a large group of persons not now subject to direct taxation and to bear the administrative burdens involved in such a task. |
||||||||||
[Next] | ||||||||||
![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() |